
ISSN: 2641-6794
Diogo José Horst*
Received: June 19, 2020; Published: July 02, 2020
Corresponding author: Diogo José Horst,Department of Mechanical Engineering and Sciences,Federal University of Santa Catarina, Brazil
DOI: 10.32474/OAJESS.2020.05.000212
This short review presents studies published in high impact journals regarding regulation mechanisms over emissions, monitoring, sequestration (capture) and carbon credits, mainly focusing on the forest sector. The search for studies was performed using the ScienceDirect and Scopus databases. A gap was identified regarding studies that present actions with the private sector, equipment and processes and urban mobilities, in contrast, several studies were found that present significant contribution on gas emissions and climate change (carbon footprint) and mathematical models on the carbon market, especially in developed countries.
Keywords: Carbon market; Greenhouse gas emissions; Environment; Climate Change; Forest Policy.
The concept of carbon credit arose from the growing awareness
of the need to reduce greenhouse gas emissions to combat global
warming, formalized in the Kyoto protocol [1]. There is a broad
consensus that humanity must reduce carbon emissions to mitigate
global warming. It is generally accepted that carbon trading is one
of the most effective market mechanisms for reducing the amount
of carbon emissions [2]. Forests are important from a climatic point
of view because they allow carbon to be sequestered, forming from
biomass or stored in forest products [3]. They act as carbon sinks,
contributing significantly to climate change mitigation efforts [4].
The environmental and livelihood benefits of forests extend
beyond mitigating climate change, reforestation programs that are
normally motivated only by carbon benefits also have the potential
to improve livelihoods, reduce gender disparities and provide noncarbon
ecosystem benefits with appropriate land selection and
involvement of local communities in governance [5]. In a long-term
perspective, the European Commission (2011) proposed a roadmap
for the transition to a competitive low-carbon economy by 2050.
This roadmap proposes reductions in green basins between 80 and
95% by 2050 compared to the 1990 level. It focuses on reaching
this cost range efficiently, implying that the inclusion of low-cost
reduction options, such as forest carbon extraction, needs to be
evaluated. However, carbon credit markets suffer from seemingly
inescapable failures that may justify alternative approaches, such
as carbon taxes, a complete elimination of carbon dioxide emissions
or a global carbon fund. In the coming years, we must remember
that credits are not the only sensible policy options for responding
to climate change [6].
Within this context, this short review study presents the
mechanisms for monitoring and regulating emissions and carbon
credits, mainly addressing the forestry sector, seeking to contribute
to the evolution of the theme.
Senadheera [5] proposes the Hiniduma Bio-link Project which is maintained by the Conservation Carbon Company in Sri Lanka. In addition to the direct benefit of protecting forests in reducing carbon emissions and increasing carbon sequestration, forest projects generate indirect benefits called co-benefits that can be linked to the national agenda for Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) and the impacts of forest carbon in forest carbon projects. Equal or more important for buyers of emission reductions. Hiniduma Bio-link offers carbon credits with added value for socially and environmentally conscious organizations and people. It is a reforestation project to establish a biodiversity corridor between two large remaining patches protected from the Sri Lankan forest - Singharaja and Kanneliya. In addition to mitigating the broader issue of climate change, the project helps to (1) conserve limited woodland forests by providing buffers and a safe corridor between the two protected forest fragments to help reduce threats to local biodiversity and wildlife in communities adjacent human activities, and (2) improve livelihoods for farmers and local landowners, providing training and income generation opportunities. The Bio- Link Project accomplishes this through the reforestation of home gardens by traditional farmers in the lowland wetland region through the concept of analog forests. Along with the baseline biomass estimate for the selected pilot phase project, the carbon savings of newly planted trees were calculated and recorded for carbon credits.
MoorFutures® is the world’s first carbon credit scheme based
on a new peat refill. So far, MoorFutures® rely on proxies (types of
greenhouse gas emission sites or GESTs to estimate emission reductions.
Günther [7] test the profitability of including direct measurements
of greenhouse gases ( GHG) of project emissions for a
range of re-humidification costs and vegetation scenarios based
on a hypothetical MoorFutures® project In almost all scenarios,
GEST assessments underestimated emission reductions compared
to direct measurements. direct measurements was profitable in>
50% of all vegetation / rehumidification scenario combinations
with net profits ranging from EUR - 8.18 to 26.31 per certificate
Profitability was achieved by recovering costs of € 5400 ha-1 for
more sophisticated GHG measurements have become profitable at
twice the cost of re-humidification. In cases where direct flow measurements
do not generate profit, they can strengthen the reliability
and reliability of buyers and thus bear higher certificate prices.
Man [8] investigated the inventory of three actively managed
forest properties located in the coastal, central interior and
northern British Forest regions to estimate the cost of producing
carbon credits ($ per carbon credit) when harvesting is reduced
below the reference level. The financial analysis was carried out
in a range of discount rates (0–16%) and the total cost included
the opportunity cost due to the reduction in the harvest and cost of
the Carbon project (the initial establishment and validation cost of
the Carbon project and the cost of continuous verification for two
frequencies (1 year and 5 years) .When the opportunity cost was
not included, the cost per Carbon credit was similar to previous
results (lower cost per carbon credit for a higher location index
(or maximum height in meters at 50 years old. However, when
the opportunity cost was included, the cost per Carbon credit was
higher for the highest site rates that corresponded to the highest
average value per hectare harvested (AVHH) ( that is, the wood
revenue multiplied by the average harvested volume per hectare
per year). The reversal of trends is the result of the average wood
revenue being higher for the higher site indexes, which resulted in
a higher cost opportunity and greater AVHH. The opportunity cost
represented 58% to 97% of the cost per carbon credit. Compared to
the 5-year verification, the 1-year verification frequency increased
the total cost per carbon credit by 1% to 22%, the smallest increase
when the cost of the carbon project represented a small percentage
of the total cost. The estimates for the three forest properties
analyzed here represent three points on a larger spectrum, and
identify the cost per carbon credit in a range of local indices (14.7
to 25.6 meters maximum height at 50 years), AVHH ( 12.2 to 63.7
thousand dollars). ha-1 year-1) and net wood revenue (US $ 4 to
US $ 35 m-3). Further research is needed to determine whether the
trends found in this study remain over a more densely populated
spectrum.
Juutinen [9] examined the feasibility and impacts of a shortterm
carbon payment mechanism on forest management in boreal
forests. Unlike long-term carbon sequestration commitments over
a rotation period, landowners can, in this scheme, sell temporary
carbon credits stored for one year and reissue them annually.
Using numerical optimization, we show that the short-term carbon
payment mechanism has a profound effect on the time and intensity
of thinning, and the optimal duration of rotation, showing itself in
higher wood yield and greater profitability. A comparison of the
case where all carbon or just additional carbon above the reference
value for wood management is accounted for by the short-term
payment scheme shows that optimal forest management remains
more or less the same. However, the increase in forestry profitability
introduced by carbon credits is relatively small, if only additional
carbon is credited. Therefore, the short-term mechanism can
only be viable at high carbon prices and would probably increase
the rotation length of mature stands with the requirement for
additionality in boreal forests.
The work from Barua [10] contributes to the economy of
deforestation, presenting a dynamic model, with an infinite formal
horizon, describing the use of tropical forest resources. As an
alternative to clearing the forest, a landowner has the option of
selling it to an international carbon credit program. The model
is used to investigate the corrective incentive programs needed
to ensure a socially optimal level of forest resources. Optimal
conditions for a land income tax and a carbon offset fee are derived.
The article shows that the optimization of national carbon offset
policies depends crucially on taxing land rent. In the presence of
an ideal land income tax subsidy program, the government may
need to pass on to owners the same carbon offset it receives from
the international community to ensure a socially optimal tropical
forest stock. However, the government may need to over-transfer
or sub-transfer carbon offset, depending on whether the preexisting
property income tax is below or above the optimal level, respectively. This suggests that the pre-existing sub-optimization
in the taxation of land rent in a given country can be corrected
by adjusting the carbon offset. Therefore, a carbon offset scheme
must take into account existing national policies that affect forest
clearing.
The country’s familiar forest lands can be an important
contributor to carbon sequestration efforts. However, very little
is known about how family forest landowners view programs that
allow them to sell carbon credits generated from the growth of their
forests and the compensation that would be needed to encourage a
significant level of participation. To address this information gap,
Miller [11] conducted a study to identify and quantify the interest
of the family’s forest landowners in participating in a voluntary
carbon market trading program in the States of Lake, USA. A mail
survey was administered to 2,200 randomly selected family forest
owners in Michigan, Wisconsin, and Minnesota. The questionnaire
assessed the interest of rural landowners in participating in a
hypothetical carbon credit trading program and sought information
on landowners’ objectives and practices, perspectives on carbon
credit programs and forest land characteristics. A total of 850
useful responses were received. A logistic regression model was
developed to examine the factors that affect participation in a forest
carbon offset project by family forest owners and to estimate the
likelihood of landowners’ participation.
The results show that the characteristics of the carbon program,
together with the characteristics of the owner and the parcel,
are associated with the decision to participate in a carbon credit
program. Specifically, amount of carbon credit payment, duration
of the contract, gender, amount placed in other non-market
forest amenities, need for additional income, attitude towards
climate change, absentee status, land tenure and total acres were
considered determinants significant. Our findings indicate that
carbon sequestration management can align with the ownership
goals of many family forest owners in the Lake States.
In Norway, family forest owners own 80% of productive forest
areas and play a central role in the management of the country’s
forests. However, little is known whether these landowners would
be interested in increasing carbon sequestration on their land and
selling carbon credits. Only a handful of studies have examined the
factors that motivate family forest owners to participate in carbon
offset programs, and all of these studies have been conducted in
the United States. Håbesland [4] addressed this information gap
using data from a mail survey of 1500 Norwegian family forest
owners. A logistic regression model was developed to examine the
effect of various characteristics of the carbon, forest and landowner
program on participation in a hypothetical carbon offset program.
The results suggest that there is a considerable amount of interest
among Norwegian family forest owners and that the most important
indicators of participation are the amount of payment offered, the
barriers perceived by management actions, the importance given to
non-market forest amenities and attitudes towards climate change.
Zhang & Li [12] carried out a risk analysis of six Chinese banks involved in carbon finance. The copulation factor is introduced to simulate the corresponding carbon finance credit risk and the market risk for latent variables in an indirect method. In short, the four common factors in carbon finance - exchange rates, interest rates, CER prices and Brent oil prices - are analyzed and explored in a copula factor approach that incorporates KMV, GARCH two-step models . KMV and GARCH models are used to generate data that reflect the overall credit and market risk associated with each bank. Both normal copula and t-copula functions are used to simulate parameter estimates for comparison in a new way. The value at risk for each of the six banks is calculated using Monte Carlo simulation and compared. In addition, we calculate shock estimates for each factor to explore changes in credit risk and market risk, given economic shocks, and we also do a hypothetical analysis of the impact of the financial crisis on common factors. Overall, our results reveal that exchange rates and oil prices are the key factors to be considered in carbon finance. Ping and Bank is facing the highest risk of all the banks in the sample, while the Industrial and Commercial Bank of China is presenting the lowest risk. The results of this analysis provided some information on the internal carbon trade and the connectivity of the carbon markets.
Kumar [13] performed the thermal and economic evaluation
of an active hybrid solar distillation system (PVT) incorporating
the subsidy effect, tax benefit, inflation and maintenance costs is
presented for the climatic condition of New Delhi (India). The
analysis is based on annualized costing and the expected life span of
15 and 30 years. In addition, CO2 emission / mitigation and revenue
from carbon credits are taken into account in accordance with the
Kyoto Protocol standards for India. The energy production factor
(EPF) and the life cycle conversion efficiency (LCCE) are 5.9% and
14.5%, respectively, for the expected useful life of 30 years. The
costs of producing energy and spirits are found at Rs. 0.85 / kWh
and Rs. 0.75 / L, respectively, accounting for earned carbon credit.
The cost payback period is estimated at 4.2 years, if the distillate is
sold at a rate of Rs. 6.0 / L in the local market.
The implementation of reverse logistics for waste electrical and
electronic equipment (WEEE) and its components has been a major
concern for the Brazilian government and the private sector in
recent decades. Caiado [14] proposes a description of the Brazilian
market for adequate disposal or reverse logistics credits (RLC)
and also an analogy with the carbon credit market. Therefore, a
descriptive research was carried out, focusing on the study of the
WEEE RLC market in Brazil. Some experts involved in this context were consulted on their perspectives for this market and the main
motivations for the environmentally appropriate disposal of WEEE.
It has been found that most stakeholders agree that the reverse
logistics credit market is a possibility, but there are currently several
obstacles to its implementation. Regarding the comparison of RLC
with the carbon credit market, there are still many aspects to be
developed before the RLC market becomes a reality. The Brazilian
RLC market still has no legal support to work with, no organization
to control and audit the market and no government support.
Agrawal & Tiwari [15] performed the performance analysis in
terms of the effect of the carbon credit earned on the uniform annualized
cost of the hybrid photovoltaic thermal air collector based on
the annual thermal energy and exergy were analyzed for the New
Delhi climatic conditions. The effect of interest rates on the annualized
uniform cost was also assessed. During the analysis of the
useful life (30 years), the reduction in carbon emissions reaches Rs
109,242 and Rs 25275.6 based on the general thermal energy and
exergy basis. It was also observed that there is a significant reduction
in the annualized uniform cost due to the carbon credit earned.
Rajoria [16] investigated a new approach in the cash flow
diagram to investigate the effect of the energy return time and
carbon credits gained in the life cycle cost of different photovoltaic
thermal panel systems, for this three types of configurations were
considered, namely: (i) opaque type PVT arrangement (case A),
(ii) solar cell arrangement (SCT) (case B) and (iii) semitransparent
arrangement (case C). The performances of all the cases above
were calculated using three basic metrics. These are the energy
return time (EPBT), the energy production factor (EPF) and the
life cycle conversion efficiency (LCCE). When the EPBT effect is
considered in the cash flow of the PVT arrangement system, the
annualized uniform cost increased by 7.0% for the lowest value and
16.5% for the highest value, both in the energy base and in the base
of exergy. The values reflected in this approach are more realistic
than the conventional approach. Considering the effect of earned
carbon credits and EPBT on the annualized uniform cost of the PVT
arrangement system, the higher value of the annualized uniform
cost is indicative of a better and more efficient system that has the
ability to offset the cost incurred in the system. It was also observed
that, among all cases, case C is a better performance in terms of
energy and exergy.
In addition to contributing to sustainable development by
recovering energy in the form of methane, carbon credits can be
claimed by applying advanced anaerobic processes in the treatment
of wastewater to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. As granular
anaerobic systems are capable of withstanding high organic loads
concomitant with high-strength effluents and short hydraulic
retention times, they could yield far more carbon credits than other
conventional anaerobic systems. As granular anaerobic systems
are capable of withstanding high organic loads concomitant
with high-strength effluents and short hydraulic retention times,
they could yield far more carbon credits than other conventional
anaerobic systems. Granular anaerobic processes have become an
attractive treatment technology option, especially for high-strength
wastewater, considering the fact that, in addition to efficient waste
degradation, carbon credits can be used to generate revenue and
finance the project .
Within this context, Show & Lee [17] present an emission
reduction scenario based on a methane recovery and use project.
An example of analysis on emission reductions and future trends is
also described. Wong [1] investigated the carbon credit potential
derived from laboratory scale anaerobic sludge blanket (UASB)
reactors based on a carbon balance analysis. The reduction in
methane emissions can be calculated by calculating the difference
in UASB reactors and open lagoon treatment systems. Based on the
bench-scale 2.5 l reactor, the total reduction in CH4 emissions was
calculated as 29 kg CO2 / year. By climbing to a typical full-scale
anaerobic digester, the total reduction in CH4 emissions could
achieve a reduction of 46,420 tons of CO2 per year. The estimated
carbon credits would be US $ 278,500 per year, assuming a carbon
price of US $ 6 per metric ton of CO2 reduction. The analysis
postulated that it is financially viable to invest in the advanced
system of granular anaerobic treatment from the revenue generated
by carbon credits.
Traffic congestion contributes to the problem of air pollution
due to increased idling, braking and acceleration behaviors. Li [18]
proposes an optimal dynamic credit collection scheme that can
redistribute traffic flows to achieve mobility and emission goals.
First, the cell transmission model is used as a dynamic network
loading model to capture the flow spread and the user’s dynamic
balance (DUE) is formulated to investigate the flow redistribution
in terms of simultaneous and departure path choices in the carbon
credit collection scheme. Based on this, a two-level formulation is
proposed to describe Stackelberg’s game between the road manager
and the road users. For the higher level, the road manager seeks to
minimize the system’s travel time and emissions by implementing
credit collection schemes. For the lower level, heterogeneous
users find the user’s dynamic balance through simultaneous
options of path and departure time under certain credit collection
schemes. Given the non-convex property of the two-level model,
this article proposes the pattern search algorithm incorporated
into the projection method. Computational results in the X-shaped
network, Ziliaskopolous and Nyguen-Dupuis are given to show the
applicability of the proposed algorithm in networks of reasonable
size. The results show that the minimum travel time design does
not always generate effective commuting and starting switches for
all user groups, especially for users with high travel time value,
while the minimum emissions credit design produces behavioral adjustments desirable. In addition, the minimum travel time credit
project does not always generate minimum carbon emissions in the
network, especially in networks with complex pairs and O-D paths.
This research sheds light on how to program a time-varying credit
collection scheme to achieve mobility and issuance targets. The
political implications of the credit collection scheme are provided.
Performance-based environmental regulation has gained
popularity as a political tool to prevent climate change. California
implements a Low Carbon Fuel Standard regulation to reduce
the average carbon intensity of fuels by 10%, without specifying
technologies to achieve the target. A carbon trading market is
established to facilitate fuel producers who generate revenue by
producing second generation low carbon renewable fuels. There is
a knowledge gap in the understanding of the interactions between
the commodities and carbon trading markets under performancebased
regulation. Hu & Chen [19] proposes a mathematical program
with an equilibrium constraints model to find the equilibrium
transport energy portfolio under the environmental protection
policy. The model uses the Karush-Kuhn-Tucker optimality
conditions to represent the profit maximization of fuel suppliers.
Profit is counted in the commodities market and in the carbon
trading market. Our results show that carbon credit encourages the
production of second-generation biofuels, which plays a critical role
in the success of the Low Carbon Fuel Standard. The price of carbon
credit is driven by compliance with carbon intensity regulations,
which we have proven through mathematical formulation and
analysis of empirical data. Reducing carbon intensity is the key to
promoting the low performance of biobutanol based on the low
carbon fuel policy. The proposed structure, with minor adjustments,
can be used to assess performance-based regulation in other fields.
While the urban forest is considered an eligible source of
carbon offset credits, little is known about its market potential and
the credit quality aspects. As credit providers increase in number
and credit buyers become more interested in buying carbon credits,
it is unclear whether and how urban forest carbon credits can
outperform other types of carbon credits available on the market.
market. The delivery of quality credits would be crucial, especially
in voluntary markets such as the USA, where buyers are more likely
to commit to reducing their GHG emissions and maintaining a
positive public image than just complying with regulations. Using
the results of a national survey of local governments Poudyal [20]
evaluated the quality aspects of urban forest carbon credits. It is
concluded that the municipalities and municipalities of the United
States, acting as sellers of carbon credits, have resources and
capacity to be competitive in the carbon credit markets. In addition,
they have the capacity and resources to implement carbon projects
that will meet the main quality criteria (for example, additionality,
permanence and verification).
The difficult social issues faced by non-governmental
organizations in relation to the planning, management and
evolution of refugee camps have led to the assessment of alternative
development strategies. In fact, innovative technologies could be
promoted to improve the local economy in a sustainable way. Manni
[21] present a model suggesting the exploitation of high-albedo
materials to generate fresh oases in warm climate contexts. The
benefits derived from this proposal were investigated by simulating
the application of high albedo devices in shelters in Zaatari, so the
avoided carbon emissions were quantified, and various scenarios
were discussed. Under the Emissions Trading System, carbon
credits, which can be obtained and sold contributing to the process
of mitigating global warming, are estimated at around 150,000 tons
of CO2-eq. Considering the market trends presented during COP21
in Paris, the intervention proved to be sustainable in economic and
environmental terms. The payback period is estimated at three
years in the most reliable scenario. The work presents the main
results of a broader research that also included considerations on
the urban planning of the camps.
The Kyoto Protocol, a global governmental response to climate change, signatories to the protocol make an effort to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions. South Korea is not included in the list of countries in Annex I; however, South Korea is the seventh largest CO2 emitter. The South Korean government has enacted a number of institutional policies to encourage reductions in greenhouse gases. Although previous studies have focused on guidance that reflects the position of suppliers in the carbon market, the study by Roh [22] focuses on the real demand of South Korean companies for forest carbon credits. When applying the contingent valuation method, we estimate the willingness of domestic companies to pay for forest carbon credits. Then, we apply a logistic regression ordered by classification to confirm whether the classification of forest carbon credits, in comparison with any other carbon credit, is influenced by the characteristics of a company. The results showed that Korean companies are willing to pay 5.45USD / t CO2 and 7.77 USD / t CO2 for forest carbon credits in national and international forest carbon projects, respectively. Therefore, the introduction of forest carbon credits in the Korean carbon market seems reasonable. The analysis of the priority rankings of forest carbon credits, however, demonstrated that forest projects were less likely to be classified by companies as their first priority. Although the relative preferences for forest carbon credits have been influenced by the individual characteristics of the companies, such as previous experience of environmental activities related to CSR and if the company has established an emission reduction plan, the impact of perceived behavior control, if the company was included in the management of emissions targets forest carbon credits scheme was insignificant. Therefore, forest carbon credits are not a viable solution without strong government support or institutional instruments. The results of this study are expected to provide policymakers with realistic approaches to formulating policies related to climate change.
The shift to renewable energy options and low-carbon technologies,
in response to concerns about energy security and climate
change, is proceeding more slowly than many would like. The usual
argument against the rapid deployment of new technologies is the
costs imposed on the economy, generally interpreted in terms of
initial costs to be borne or involving large transfers of money to
finance, for example, efforts to preserve tropical forests. Mathews
[23] argues that such a perspective provides a continuous barrier
to effective action, while a perspective based on the creation and
use of carbon credits provides a means of avoiding the shock of
abrupt industrial changes. Carbon credits granted for carbon load
reductions in good faith could be created through private initiative,
for example, by commercial banks, to constitute a market that will
complement regulatory-based initiatives, such as national emissions
trading systems. This is not a new idea; in fact, it is the way in
which capitalism has financed all major changes, including the Industrial
Revolution, through the creation of credit. The emergence
of a global carbon credit economy is likely to precede a global regulatory
system that governs climate change and will undoubtedly
help to stimulate the emergence of such a global system.
The Paris Agreement establishes a mechanism that allows
a Party to benefit from reductions in greenhouse gas emissions
conducted in a host Party to fulfill its nationally determined
contribution. In this context, Gavard & Kirat [24] aimed to improve
the understanding of carbon offset pricing dynamics compared to
regular carbon market concessions. We combine a cointegration
approach with risk premium considerations to compare the price
dynamics of European Union (US) Permits and Certified Emission
Reductions (CER) in the second phase of the European carbon
market. Taking into account the breaks identified in the series, we
found that, although the US and CER return a comparable dynamic
mainly driven by fuel switching, the long-term relationships
between the price of these two types of allowances and their
drivers differ significantly. While the US price is well explained
by a demand effect, the impact of energy prices on the CER price
suggests that there is an supply-side effect for credits. We note that
the price elasticity of allowances in relation to coal and gas prices is
negative in periods of low economic activity and positive during the
remaining time. We explain the first with the fact that the market is
not tight and the second with the effect of economic activity on the
price of commodities and energy.
The internal rate of return (IRR) is a tool widely used in the
classification of capital budget projects and eventual decisions
of acceptance or rejection. In their study Dhavale & Sarkis [25]
considered an investment decision involving a sustainable, energyefficient,
greenhouse gas (GHG) reduction asset incorporating the
value of carbon emission allowances for the investing company.
These concessions create cash flows that can be characterized by
significant volatility and uncertainty. The methodology developed
in this document allows decision makers to integrate their
knowledge of carbon trading markets and the cash flows that result
from the sale of emissions credits. The new methodology uses a
Bayesian model for IRR that uses a Gibbs sampler. The analysis of
the results shows that the IRR is influenced by the volatility and
uncertainty of cash flows from carbon credits. Ignoring these
characteristics of uncertainty and simply using the expected cash
flow values can result in a significantly inaccurate rate of return
on investment. When compared to deterministic IRR calculations,
the results show that the occurrence of very high and very low
cash flows positively affects the IRR, while the greater variability
in the cash flow distribution negatively affects the IRR of the GHGreducing
asset. In other words, frequent large or small cash flows
are preferred over floating cash flows. The results can also provide
a justification for the existence of anomalous consumer behavior,
known as the energy efficiency gap.
Dye & Yang [26] carried out a study on credit decisions and
sustainable trade replacement with demand linked to credit under
carbon emission restrictions considering sustainability issues in
the context of joint commercial credit and inventory management
where demand depends on duration the credit period offered
by the retailer to its customers. We quantify the impacts of the
crediting period and environmental regulations on the inventory
model. Starting with some moderate assumptions, we first analyze
the model with widespread demand and default risk rates under
the Carbon Cap-and-Trade policy, and then make some extensions
to the model with the Carbon Compensation policy. We further
analyzed the effects of carbon emission parameters on the retailer’s
credit and commercial replacement strategies. Finally, a pair of
numerical examples and sensitivity analysis are given to illustrate
the characteristics of the proposed model, which is followed by
final observations.
Hua [2] investigated how companies manage carbon footprints
in inventory management under the carbon emissions trading
mechanism. We obtain the optimal quantity of orders and analyze
analytically and numerically the impacts of carbon trading, the
price of carbon and the carbon cap on order decisions, carbon
emissions and total cost. We make interesting observations
from the numerical examples and provide managerial insights
from the analytical results. The imminent risks associated with
climate change have forced the global community to devise a
marketable pollution permit or “cap and trade” approaches to
control the release of greenhouse gases. In the USA, soils have the
potential to offset about 10% of annual CO2 emissions; however, if carbon credits are included in greenhouse gas control programs,
the organic carbon sequestration rates (SOC) associated with
agricultural land uses must be computed on a hydrographic basin
scale. In this context, used the water quality model of the Soil
Water Assessment Tool (SWAT), the erosion model of the Water
Erosion Prediction Project (WEPP) and the carbon model CENTURY
4.0 soil to simulate carbon sequestration rates in 160 sub-basins in
the Big Creek basin (, 312,300 hectares). In annual crops, only notillage
in corn-soybean rotation, on low to moderate slopes, results
in net gains in SOC. Substantial annual rates of SOC sequestration
occur only under perennial crops, such as Conservation Reserve
(PCR; 0.14 t / ha without erosion; 0.08 with erosion), pasture
(0.67 t / ha without erosion; 0.58 with erosion), hay (0.88 t / ha
without erosion; 0.52 with erosion) and forest (2.66 t / ha without
erosion; 2.49 with erosion). Erosion therefore has a great effect
on the spatial distribution of SOC measured in the field, moving it
downwards and increasing its spatial variability. For this reason,
carbon credit programs must be based on field practices, thus
targeting the locations where atmospheric carbon sequestration
actually occurs and minimizing monitoring costs. The development
of estimates based on rate models for hijacking field activities in
many locations would thus serve, to a large extent, the needs of
carbon credit programs.
Van Voorhees [27] studied what must be done to obtain credit for the amounts of carbon dioxide inevitably stored in association with improved carbon dioxide recovery (CO2 -EOR). The study explores this issue with special emphasis on several recent developments in December 2015 that will directly affect responses to this question in the context of the United States Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) regulatory scheme to control greenhouse gas emissions (GHG). In 2015, the EPA finalized a fundamental regulatory framework for the control of GHG emissions from generating units powered by fossil fuels, new and existing. In doing so, the EPA conditioned the use of CCS in quantifying stored carbon dioxide through reports from Subpart RR of the reporting requirements of Part 98 GHG, the reporting approach developed primarily for geological sequestration in salt formations. And the Subpart RR report would be required regardless of whether carbon dioxide storage is achieved through geological sequestration or in association with enhanced carbon dioxide oil (CO2 -EOR) recovery. Numerous concerns were raised in comments on the proposed rules and in response to the final rules on the ability of EOR operations to meet Subpart RR reporting requirements, and from 2010 to 2015 no one reported under Subpart RR because all projects injecting the carbon dioxide in salt formations qualified for research exemptions, and no EOR operation had voluntarily chosen to report under subpart RR instead of subparts W and UU.
Yu & Mallori examined the impact of exchange rates on the
carbon market. We analyzed this effect through the European
Union’s Emissions Trading Scheme (EU-ETS), which mainly uses
two replaceable fossil energy inputs for electricity generation: coal
and natural gas. The European coal market is driven directly by the
global coal markets that are denominated in USD, while natural gas
is imported mainly from Russia and is denominated in Euros. The
impulse response functions of a structural vector autoregression
model (SVAR) demonstrate that a shock in the euro / dollar
exchange rate can be transmitted through the energy substitution
channel between coal and natural gas and influence in the carbon
credit market .
Feng [28] examined the carbon price volatility using data from
the European Union’s Emissions Trading Scheme from the point of
view of nonlinear dynamics. First, we use a random walk model,
including serial correlation and rate of variance tests, to determine
whether historical carbon price information is fully reflected in
the current carbon price. The results of the empirical research
show that the carbon price is not a random walk: historical price
information is not fully reflected in the current carbon price.
Second, use R / S, modified R / S and ARFIMA to analyze the
history of carbon price history. For the period from April 2005 to
December 2008, the modified Hurst index of the carbon price is
0.4859 and the value of d ARFIMA is -0.1191, indicating the shortterm
memory of the carbon price. Third, we use chaos theory to
analyze the influence of the internal carbon market mechanism on
the carbon price, that is, the positive and negative market feedback
mechanism and the heterogeneous environment. Chaos theory
proves that the correlation dimension of the carbon price increases.
Lyapunov’s maximum exponent is positive and large. There is no
obvious complex endogenous phenomenon of nonlinear dynamics
to carbon price fluctuation. The carbon market is slightly chaotic,
showing the characteristics of the market and the fractal market.
The price fluctuation is not only influenced by the internal market
mechanism but is also affected by the heterogeneous environment.
Finally, we offer suggestions for regulation and development of the
carbon market.
Ibrahim & Kalaitzoglou [29] investigated why carbon prices
and price volatility change. The authors proposed a microstructural
pricing model for asymmetric information, in which the price
responses to information and liquidity vary according to each
transaction. Bid-ask quotations and price components are
responsible for learning, incorporating expectations of change in the
volume traded rate (trading intensity) and the risk level of incoming
trades. The analysis of future carbon transactions in Europe
considers that the expected intensity of trading simultaneously
increases the information component and decreases the liquidity
component of price changes, but at different rates. This explains
some conflicting results in the previous literature. In addition, the
expected persistence in trading intensity explains most of the level’s
autocorrelations and the conditional variation of the price change;
helps to predict hourly patterns in returns, variation and bid-ask spread; and differentiates the impact of purchase price versus sale
and continuity versus business reversal.
The study by Chevallier [30] is the first non-parametric
modeling exercise applied to the carbon markets. The analysis
chart is carefully detailed, and the empirical application unfolds in
the case of Blue Next spot and ECX future prices. Data are collected
on a daily basis from April 2005 to April 2010. First, we document
the presence of strong nonlinearities in the functions of conditional
means. Second, the conditional volatility functions reveal an
asymmetric and heteroscedastic behavior that is dramatically
different between carbon returns and future returns. The results
for spot prices are also robust to the decomposition of subsamples.
Third, we showed in an out-of-sample forecasting exercise that
non-parametric modeling allows to reduce the prediction error
by almost 15% compared to linear RA models. This latter result is
confirmed by the Diebold-Marian pair-by-pair test statistic.
Following Chevallier [31] develops a carbon pricing model
considering two fundamental factors of European Union permits:
economic activity and energy prices. On the one hand, economic
activity is represented by aggregated industrial production in the
EU-27 (as it provides the best performance in a preliminary forecast
exercise vs. other indicators). On the other hand, oil, natural gas
and coal prices are selected as the main carbon price vectors (as
highlighted by the previous literature). The interactions between
the macroeconomic and energy spheres are captured in a two-state
Markov change VAR model that is capable of reproducing the boombust
business cycle. First, it appears that industrial production
positively (negatively) impacts the carbon market during periods
of economic expansion (recession), thus confirming the existence
of a link between macroeconomics and the price of carbon. Second,
the price of crude oil is confirmed as a leader in the formation of
prices between the energy markets, since it impacts other variables
through the structure of the Markov-switching model. Together,
these results reveal new interactions between the newly created
EU emissions market and the pre-existing macroeconomic / energy
environment.
The aim of the study by Guðbrandsdóttir & Haraldsson [35]
was to examine what drives changes in the price of carbon credits
in the European Union’s Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) and
to make predictions based on these relationships. The study is
based on the United Kingdom (UK) energy market data set and
global stock indices. The large data set is reduced in size using
correlation analysis and predictions are made by multiple linear
regression. Certified emission reduction units (CERs) prove to
be the only market relationship on the same day that provides
useful forecasts of European Union allowance prices (EUAs). No
significant correlation is found between EUAs and the UK energy
market and the theoretical price of carbon credits; switching price
is a bad indicator of the price of carbon credits.
Carbon-restricted energy planning (CCEP) is a relatively new
area of research dedicated to working with the regional carbon
dioxide (CO2) emissions limit through the implementation of
various low-carbon technologies. One of these technologies is
carbon capture and storage (CCS). Ooi & Foo [33] demonstrated the
use of a recently proposed automated targeting (ATM) model for
exchanging carbon credits (commonly known as “carbon emissions
trading”), which is a growing interest among many parties that are
required emission reduction commitments. A hypothetical example
is used for illustration.
The study by Barros and Tiago Filho [34] aimed to obtain
preliminary estimates on the potential of carbon credits for projects
of Small Hydroelectric Plants (PCHs) in the Brazilian panorama,
which was divided into two phases. In Phase I, a comparative
analysis was carried out of the accumulated CO2 emission values
due to the expansion of the annual gross coal sources and the
accumulated CO2 emission values of the expansion of the installed
gross annual capacity of SHPP for two scenarios, Scenario 1 and
Scenario 2 The results demonstrated the advantages of using PCH as
an energy source, with regard to greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions,
despite the uncertainty of the values of the GHG emission factors.
Phase II presents a case study based on data from a real-time series
for a station located in the south of Minas Gerais, with an arbitrary
value for the project’s head of the project [35-50]. The calculation
of the Stay Power, Energy Curve and values of Optimal Hydraulic
Power Available (MW) and Optimal Flow Available (m3/s) was
possible thanks to the Microsoft®Excel® spreadsheet of CERPCH
[11]. The calculation of net profit derived from carbon credit for
SHP projects was done using the Microsoft®Excel® spreadsheet by
Michellis Junior 18, based on the CDM guidelines, as recommended
in the United Nations Convention on Climate Change, Ministry of
Science and technology [51-61]. The results showed that the net
revenues obtained by carbon credits in SHP projects located in the
Isolated System were well above those obtained in the National
Interconnected System.
This review study presents works published in high impact journals regarding carbon footprints, showing the main regulating mechanisms for monitoring, emissions, sequestration, and carbon credits, covering mainly the forestry sector. The search for studies was carried out using the ScienceDirect and Scopus scientific databases. As a main result, a gap was identified regarding studies that present actions with the private sector, equipment and processes and urban mobilities, in contrast, several studies were found that present a significant contribution on gas emissions and climate change (carbon footprint) and models mathematicians about the carbon market, mainly in developed countries.
This study received financial support from the Coordination for the Improvement of Higher Education Personnel - CAPES, Brazil, financial code [001].
Bio chemistry
University of Texas Medical Branch, USADepartment of Criminal Justice
Liberty University, USADepartment of Psychiatry
University of Kentucky, USADepartment of Medicine
Gally International Biomedical Research & Consulting LLC, USADepartment of Urbanisation and Agricultural
Montreal university, USAOral & Maxillofacial Pathology
New York University, USAGastroenterology and Hepatology
University of Alabama, UKDepartment of Medicine
Universities of Bradford, UKOncology
Circulogene Theranostics, EnglandRadiation Chemistry
National University of Mexico, USAAnalytical Chemistry
Wentworth Institute of Technology, USAMinimally Invasive Surgery
Mercer University school of Medicine, USAPediatric Dentistry
University of Athens , GreeceThe annual scholar awards from Lupine Publishers honor a selected number Read More...